ECON 4643: Development Economics

Lecture 7: Module 2-Education

Author

Harounan Kazianga
Oklahoma State University
Spring 2024

Code
if (!require("pacman")) install.packages("pacman")
Loading required package: pacman
Code
pacman::p_load(haven, DescTools, knitr, kableExtra, ineq, ggplot2, formatdown, tidyverse, WDI, latex2exp, stargazer, lmtest, sandwich)

Reading

    • Orazem, Peter F. and King, Elizabeth M., 2008. “Schooling in Developing Countries: The Roles of Supply, Demand and Government Policy,’” in Handbook of Development Economics

Introduction

  • Education and health are important objectives of development

    • Education and health are also important components of growth and development – inputs in the aggregate production function

    • Universal primary school attendance a stated goal by many governments and development agencies.

    • Increasing educational attainment is believed to be one of the most effective ways of tackling poverty

  • At the micro level, several studies link education and individual earnings

  • At the macro level, pioneering work found a strong link between economic growth and human capital (e.g. Mankiw et al. 1992; Lucas, 1988) recently.

  • Enrollment low but varying across countries

  • Wide gap between rural and urban areas

  • Wide gap between boys and girls

  • Education and health are investments in the same individual

  • Greater health capital may improve the returns to investments in education

    • Health is a factor in school attendance

    • Healthier students learn more effectively

    • A longer life raises the rate of return to education

    • Healthier people have lower depreciation of education capital

  • Greater education capital may improve the returns to investments in health

  • Public health programs need knowledge learned in school

  • Basic hygiene and sanitation may be taught in school

  • Education needed in training of health personnel

Relevant Questions

  • In what ways to do governments and NGOs intervene in the areas of primary and secondary education?

  • How do education policies fit into larger development strategies?

Economics of education

  • How do education policies alter people’s opportunities and constraints?

    • By altering the menu of options for purchasing or obtaining education,

    • where options are defined by

      -location, type, quality, language, schedule, admissions standards or eligibility criteria

      • fees, scholarships, conditional transfers

      • education promotion campaigns

  • Households are directly affected by education policy reforms if their children are enrolled in the affected schools either before or after the reform.

Economics of education: overview

  • We will need to study:

    • School enrollment decisions

    • Governance and the quality of teaching and learning

    • Direct and indirect impacts of schooling

    • Market and institutional failures in education provision

    • The differentiated effects of education policy reforms

Parents school enrollment decisions

  • A household sends a particular child to school in a given year if the household’s decision makers expect the private benefits of doing so to outweigh the private costs, including the costs of financing the investment.

  • What kinds of benefit might parents derive from sending children to school?

  • What kinds of costs might parents associate with sending a child to school?

  • Why might some parents perceive lower returns or higher costs of schooling than others?

  • Why might some parents perceive that the returns to schooling girls are lower or the costs higher than for boys?

  • What kinds of policies might be useful for getting more children into school?

  • What do we learn from empirical evidence regarding the policies that might be effective for getting more children into school?

Governance and the quality of teaching and learning (Orazem and King, 2008)

  • Education policy implementation outcomes:

Supply side

  • Number and location of schools

  • Content and language of instruction

  • Quality of teaching

  • Comfort and security

Demand side

  • Fees and contributions

  • Scholarships, school meals, conditional cash transfers

  • Promotion campaigns

  • Efficiency, waste and corruption

Examples of government policies

  • Increase supply of education services: school buildings, well trained teachers, etc
  • Increase demand of education by households: subsidies (e.g. school feeding, cash transfers), law banning child labor, compulsory education until certain age etc.

A Basic Model for Analyzing Government Interventions

  • Let \(0 \leq E^{D} \leq 1\) be the average levels of education desired by households (demand for education)

  • Let \(0 \leq E^{S} \leq 1\) be the average share of child time for which a school space is available (supply of education)

  • Demand for education depends on education price (\(P\)), (child) wage (\(w\)), and parents income (\(y\)) \[ E^{D}= \eta \left\{P+w \right\}+\theta y \]

  • \(\eta <0\) is the price elasticity of demand for schooling, and \(\theta>0\) is income elasticity of the demand for schooling.

  • Supply of education (spaces in schools) depends positively on its price (\(P\)) and negatively on its costs (\(c\)).

\[ E^{S}= \varepsilon p+\varphi c \]

Introducing government policies

  • Subsidy \(0\) \(\leq\) \(V\) \(\leq\) \(1\) : which lower the price of school that households pay

  • Conditional income transfer \(0\) \(\leq\) \(B\) \(\leq\) \(1\) : transfer is made conditional on the child attending school

  • Unconditional income transfer \(0\) \(\leq\) \(T\) \(\leq\) \(1\) : changes the ability to pay for school but does not require that the child attend school

  • School costs subsidies \(S\)

  • Demand and supply equations:

\[\begin{eqnarray*} E^{D}&=& \eta \left[(1-V)P+(1-B)w \right]+\theta (1+T)y \\ E^{S}&=& \varepsilon P+\varphi (1-S)c \\ \end{eqnarray*}\]

Equilibrium without government intervention

  • No government interventions is equivalent to \(V=S=B=T=0\)

  • Solve for \(P\) and \(E\):

\[ P^{*}=\frac{\varphi c-\eta w-\theta y}{\eta-\varepsilon} \]

\[ E^{*}=\frac{\eta \varphi c-\varepsilon \eta w-\varepsilon \theta y}{\eta-\varepsilon} \]

  • Equilibrium level of education is: \[ E^{*}=\varepsilon P^{*}+\varphi c \]

  • The first term is positive if \(P^{*}>0\), but the second term is negative

  • Hence positive equilibrium price is necessary but not sufficient to ensure positive education investments in the absence of government interventions.

Exploring government interventions

  • School costs subsidies: \(S>0\), and \(V=T=B=0\)

\[ \frac{\partial E^{*}}{\partial S}=\frac{- \eta \varphi c}{\eta-\varepsilon}>0 \]

  • The equilibrium rises unambiguously with costs subsidies.

  • Unconditional cash transfers: \(T>0\), and \(S=V=B=0\)

\[ \frac{\partial E^{*}}{\partial T}=\frac{-\varepsilon \theta y}{\eta-\varepsilon}>0 \]

  • This is positive.

  • Most effective when: school demand is income elastic but not price elastic and school supply is price elastic so that more spaces can be added without raising schooling price quickly.

  • Conditional cash transfers: \(B>0\), and \(T=V=S=0\)

\[ \frac{\partial E^{*}}{\partial B}=\frac{\eta \varepsilon w}{\eta-\varepsilon}>0 \]

  • The effect is positive, reflecting a substitution effect away from child labor and toward schooling.

  • For some households income increases, but for other households income decrease as child time is allocated away from labor

  • If income effect is positive, then both income and substitution effects reinforce each other

  • If income effect is negative then it works to offset the substitution effect, but overall effect will still be positive if the income effect is small enough.

Conditional and unconditional cash transfers within the household

  • This assumes that the income and price effects apply equally to all children in the family, but:

    • Parents can choose to enroll only some of their children, and then the question who get(s) to be enrolled?
  • Akresh, de Walque and Kazianga (2024) use experimental data to show that:

    • Conditional cash transfers most effective at getting parents to invest in outcomes/children they normally would not (“marginalized children”): girls, low ability, not enrolled at baseline, young, worse health

    • Conditional and unconditional cash transfer same impact for “non-marginalized” children: boys, high ability, enrolled at baseline, older, better health

EducationFig1
  • In figure @EducationFig1 :

  • Marginalized child = one who does not enroll or has a lower tendency to enroll in school absent an external intervention

  • Non-marginalized child is one that the household would be more likely to enroll

    • Examples of “marginalized children”: Girls; Not enrolled at baseline; Younger children (due to late start)

    • Also low ability children: evidence at baseline that households invest strategically in more able kids (Akresh, Bagby, de Walque, and Kazianga 2012)

  • For non-marginalized children, conditionality of CCT is not binding, so conditionality does not induce any change in behavior. CCT is equivalent to UCT as both shift up household budget constraint and operate through income effects

  • For marginalized children, conditionality can change behavior as parents enroll these marginalized children and make sure they attend at least 90% of the time

  • Predictions (testable)

  1. CCTs increase education more for marginalized children than UCTs

  2. UCT and CCT interventions have similar effects on the education of non-marginalized children

Exogoneous Shocks and Education

  • Economists and policy makers are often interested on what happens to education when circumstances change suddenly

    • For natural reasons: diseases, drought, flooding, etc

    • For man-made reasons: wars, displacements, etc.

  • The subject has been researched extensively

    • I show how to use simple demand and supply curves to describe these types, see Saing and Kazianga (2019)
    • The authors study “The Long-Term Impacts of Violent Conflicts on Human Capital: US Bombing and, Education, Earnings, Health, Fertility and Marriage in Cambodia”

EducationFig4
  • Initial supply and demand of education is \(S_1\) and \(D_1\), with an initial equilibrium at \(E_1\), and the number of children in school at \(Q_{E1}\).

  • Destruction of schools (because of the bombing) and displacement of teachers shift the the supply of education services to \(S_2\).

  • Population displacement and safety concerns mean that fewer children are sent to school, thus the demand for education shifts from \(D_1\) to \(D_2\).

  • The new equilibrium is at \(E_2\) with number of children in school at \(Q_{E2}\)

  • Remark that $Q_{E2} < \(Q_{E1}\), so there are fewer children in school because the bombing campaign

Assignment